Public services
tend to be seen as guarantors of well-being. Whether we think of education, healthcare or essential local services, it is generally agreed that public
services, funded by taxation and available to people regardless of their
ability to directly pay, play a role in protecting certain minimum standards.
As soon as we move however beyond these basic assumptions, debates around
public services become more antagonistic, with competing arguments regarding
the most efficient use of public funds, the most effective modes of delivery
and the main priorities of service provision. It is thus not surprising that
reform plans for public services are subject to controversial and often
contradictory claims as to what should be done, can be done and why.
It is one of
the tasks of social scientists to reveal what lies behind such arguments and to
hence analyse the material and ideological drivers behind social
transformations or policy change. To do this well, it makes sense to rely on an
effective combination of empirical research and theorising, with the latter
being essential to reduce the complexity of social reality and to create
frameworks, models and categories that help to foster a critical understanding
of the social world surrounding us.
Based on
empirical research of public service reforms and having taught this topic for several
years, I would argue that we can identify four distinct ideational frameworks,
which represent a coherent set of beliefs guiding public service reform. In
this blog post, I would like to briefly introduce these four and invite any
comments, either publicly or via email:
The social-holistic framework sees public
services as deeply interwoven with the integrative fabric of a society, as
institutions that tie social groups, individuals and communities together by
establishing bonds of collectively organised mutual support and
interdependence. The importance of public services goes beyond the practical,
as they represent one major expression of how a society chooses to be organised
along the lines of democratic inclusiveness as well as inter-generational and
inter-personal solidarity. Public services are, from this perspective and in the
words of Castel and Haroche (2001), a form of social property accessible
to all citizens and residents.
The political-selective framework is
equally embedded in material social relations, but it is less universal and
comprehensive than the previous framework, as it focuses on the conflictual
interplays between social groups. The shape and generosity of public services
as well as the priorities of service delivery are determined by the ability of
social groups and classes to influence the policy process and to make demands
for service provision.
The economic-functionalist framework
defines public services negatively, as a response to perceived gaps and
distortions in the functioning of markets. Wherever market failures occur, a
space for legitimate government intervention opens up to address said market
failures, but the scope of public services remains generally restricted to
those realms where market-based approaches, according to the theoretical
premises of this perspective, appear as insufficient.
The moral-residual framework takes this
thinking further, by stipulating that public services ought to provide nothing
more than a minimum safety net for the poorest members of society, in other
words for those who do not possess the economic or social capital to protect
themselves, for example by purchasing private education or health insurance. It
could be argued that this framework represents a sub-set of the economic-functionalist
framework, if it weren’t for one substantial difference: Similar to means-tested
benefits, users of these residual public services can potentially be subjected
to a moralising discourse that defines any reliance on the minimum safety net
as a sign of personal failure.
These four
frameworks obviously need to be fine-tuned by further empirical research in
order to create proper ideal-types, but I think they can serve well as a
starting point for analyses that seek to identify how advocates of public
service reform, be it political parties, think tanks or NGOs, conceptualise and
act upon public services.
In this way,
we can gain a deeper understanding of the underpinning ideas and interests that
drive policy change in this particular field. Moreover, it becomes easier to
identify broader trends in public service reform and to situate specific case
studies within these trends, going beyond categories such as ‘choice and
competition’ that are frequently used by observers and policy-makers to
describe reform processes. And finally, frameworks like these, or adjusted
versions of them, should enable us to shine a brighter spotlight on the
intellectual premises that underpin debates about public services.
It seems to me this critical engagement is crucial in times when the neoliberal
and managerial paradigms of the past, despite their obvious
flaws and failures, continue to restrict policy debates.
Castel, R. and Haroche, C. (2001). Propriété privée, propriété sociale, propriété de soi. Paris: Librairie Artème Fayard.
Hi Enrico, can you expand a little on where political dominance fits into the equation. When you describe the political-selective framework you states how social groups and classes make demands for public services. Yet it appears to me that those with political dominance increasingly ration public services in line with their beliefs?. Is this just a negative part of the political selective framework? Given the limitations of democratic or other political engagement I am really interested how power interacts and is interwoven in your framework.
ReplyDeleteThanks a lot, GF, for the comment and question.
DeleteI would argue that power is an overarching force that impacts on all four frameworks. In other words, which framework(s) are the most dominant depends (among other factors) on who are influential agents and on their power resources.
The particularity of the political-selective framework is that there is no view of public services that defines their scope in a broad sense, rather the shape of public services depends on the 'negotiations' between different social groups.
Having said all that, your comment makes me wonder whether keeping the political-selective framework as a distinct ideal-type is that useful. Will mull it over, thanks again for this inspiring comment.
Best, Enrico